X

Thank you for sharing!

Your article was successfully shared with the contacts you provided.

Before WIENER, GRAVES, and HO, Circuit Judges. JAMES C. HO, Circuit Judge:* Alexander Hamilton was non-stop. There were a million things he wanted done. So when he was chosen for the Constitutional Convention, he spoke like he was running out of time. He talked for six hours. The Convention was listless. And among his ideas was the power to tax exports. But the Southern states feared export taxes would disproportionately harm their economies. They worried Congress would tax them relentlessly, and then turn around and run a spending spree. They knew that, if Congress could tax exports, it would not be a question of if, but of which one. So they demanded a categorical ban on export taxes. They knew they would have to holler just to be heard. But they would rather be divisive than indecisive. So they didn’t throw away their shot. They made an all-out stand: No ban on export taxes, no Constitution. Northern delegates expressed their disgust—but the South’s agenda was there discussed. The North wanted to tax exports and regulate commerce. But the South wanted neither. The delegates were diametrically opposed—foes. But they took a break. And they eventually emerged with a compromise, having open doors that were previously closed: The federal government could regulate commerce, but not tax exports. The compromise no doubt frustrated many citizens. But they had no say in what their leaders traded away—they weren’t in the room where it happened. A group of delegates suggested another approach—export taxes only if approved on a super-majority vote—hoping that would be enough. But the South was not satisfied. It worried that, if it stood for nothing, what would it fall for? So rather than wait for it, they let the proposal burn. Ultimately, though, Hamilton got more than he gave. And he wanted what he got. But as for the power to tax exports, he was helpless. As a result, the Constitution forbids Congress from taxing exports. And that resolves this case. The federal government insists that Trafigura Trading must pay a tax on domestic crude oil that it exports from the United States. But the district court said no to this. We affirm.[1] I. The Constitutional Convention began in Philadelphia on May 25, 1787. 1 Max Farrand, ed., THE RECORDS OF THE FEDERAL CONVENTION OF 1787, at 1 (1966). Hamilton did not speak during the first few weeks of the Convention. But “[i]t was predictable that when the wordy Hamilton broke silence, he would do so at epic length.” Ron Chernow, ALEXANDER HAMILTON 231 (2004). “On Monday morning, June 18, the thirty-two-year-old prodigy rose first on the convention floor and in the stifling, poorly ventilated room he spoke and spoke and spoke. Before the day was through, he had given a six-hour speech (no break for lunch) that was brilliant, courageous, and, in retrospect, completely daft.” Id. In that speech, Hamilton set forth his vision for a strong central government, armed with a number of powers that had been omitted in the Articles of Confederation. In particular, he was the first delegate to suggest that the new federal government should have a broad power to tax that would specifically include exports: “Whence then is the national revenue to be drawn? from Commerce, even {from} exports which notwithstanding the common opinion are fit objects of moderate taxation.” 1 Farrand, supra, at 286. The power to tax exports was endorsed by a number of fellow delegates. James Madison agreed that “the power of taxing exports is proper in itself, and as the States cannot with propriety exercise it separately, it ought to be vested in them collectively.” 2 Farrand, supra, at 306. Gouverneur Morris likewise affirmed that “[t]axes on exports are a necessary source of revenue.” Id. at 307. James Wilson was also “decidedly agst prohibiting general taxes on exports,” id., for “[t]o deny this power is to take from the Common Govt. half the regulation of trade,” id. at 362. But Southern delegates were firmly opposed to export taxes. The South was the nation’s primary exporter, so any federal export tax would disproportionately burden Southern states. See, e.g., Erik M. Jensen, The Export Clause, 6 FLA. TAX REV. 1, 8 (2003). Southerners feared that the North would control the majority of seats in both Houses of Congress, and would use that power to aggrandize itself at the South’s expense by taxing exports. As George Mason put it, “a majority when interested will oppress the minority. If we compare the States in this point of view the 8 Northern States have an interest different from the five Southn. States, — and have in one branch of the legislature 36 votes agst 29. and in the other, in the proportion of 8 agst 5.” 2 Farrand, supra, at 362. So a number of Southern delegates voiced firm opposition to the Constitution unless it explicitly prohibited taxes on exports. Charles Pinckney warned that, “if the Committee [of Detail] should fail to insert some security to the Southern States agst taxes on exports, he shd. Be bound by duty to his State to vote agst. their Report.” Id. at 95. His fellow South Carolina delegate Pierce Butler likewise made clear that “he never would agree to the power of taxing exports.” Id. at 374. Northern delegates soon appreciated that, as Roger Sherman of Connecticut put it, “[a] power to tax exports would shipwreck the whole.” Id. at 308. There would be no Constitution, then, unless the delegates reached a compromise on the question of export taxes. They did so by trading the power to tax exports for the power to regulate commerce. Specifically, the South wanted to prohibit export taxes and impose a super-majority voting rule for commercial regulations, while the North wanted to permit export taxes and require only a simple majority to regulate commerce. See Ben Baack et al., Constitutional Agreement During the Drafting of the Constitution: A New Interpretation, 38 J. LEGAL STUD. 533, 546–47 (2009). So a deal was struck: A group of Northern delegates agreed that they would vote to prohibit export taxes, and in return, a group of Southern delegates agreed that they would vote for the simple majority rule for regulations of commerce. Id. at 541 (citing sources). When the Convention returned to these topics for a final vote, a group of delegates tried to revive the power to tax exports. They proposed a super-majority voting rule for export taxes, “requiring the concurrence of 2/3 or 3/4 of the legislature in such cases.” 2 Farrand, supra, at 359. Madison formally moved “to require 2/3 of each House to tax exports — as a lesser evil than a total prohibition.” Id. at 363. But the proposal failed, with every Southern delegation voting in the negative. Id. Another proposal would have allowed export taxes for the purpose of regulating trade, while prohibiting such taxes “for the purpose of revenue.” Id. But that too failed. Id. The Convention eventually adopted the language that now appears in Article I, Section 9 of the Constitution: “No Tax or Duty shall be laid on Articles exported from any State.” U.S. CONST. art. I, § 9, cl. 5. The Supreme Court has repeatedly recognized the importance as well as the breadth of the Export Clause. As the Court observed in one of the primary precedents we examine today, “the Export Clause categorically bars Congress from imposing any tax on exports.” United States v. U.S. Shoe Corp., 523 U.S. 360, 363 (1998). “[T]he Export Clause allows no room for any federal tax, however generally applicable or nondiscriminatory, on goods in export transit.” Id. at 367. It is a “simple, direct, unqualified prohibition” on any tax on exports. Id. at 368. See also Fairbank v. United States, 181 U.S. 283, 290–93 (1901) (observing that it is “obvious” from the text and history of the Export Clause “that the National Government should put nothing in the way of burden upon . . . exports”); A.G. Spalding & Bros. v. Edwards, 262 U.S. 66, 70 (1923) (recognizing that exports enjoy “liberal protection” from taxation); United States v. Int’l Bus. Machs. Corp., 517 U.S. 843, 860 (1996) (“there is substantial evidence from the [Convention] Debates that proponents of the Clause fully intended the breadth of scope that is evident in the language”).[2] II. Trafigura Trading is a commodity trading company that purchases and exports crude oil from the United States. Between 2014 and 2017, Trafigura exported around 50 million barrels of crude oil from oilfields in Texas, Louisiana, and North Dakota. Trafigura remitted over $4 million to the IRS for these exports, as required by 26 U.S.C. § 4611(b). That provision imposes a “tax”—at a rate of 8 or 9 cents per barrel, depending on the year— on domestic crude oil “used in or exported from the United States.” Id. § 4611(b)–(c)(2)(B). Proceeds from § 4611(b) go to the Oil Spill Liability Trust Fund. See id. § 9509(b)(1). The Fund serves several functions. To begin with, the Fund operates “much like insurance for the oil transportation industry”: Parties pay into the Fund via § 4611(b), and if they are ever liable for the cleanup costs of an oil spill under 33 U.S.C. § 2702, the Fund reimburses them for all expenses above a statutory cap. In re Frescati Shipping Co., 886 F.3d 291, 308 n.24 (3rd Cir. 2018), aff’d sub nom. CITGO Asphalt Ref. Co. v. Frescati Shipping Co., 140 S. Ct. 1081 (2020). But that’s not all. The Fund also covers costs incurred by federal, state, and Indian tribe trustees for natural resource damage assessment and restoration; removal costs of discharged oil from foreign offshore units; and related administrative, operational, and personnel expenses. 33 U.S.C. § 2712(a). More still, the Fund supports, among other things, research and development for oil pollution technology; studies into oil pollution’s effects; marine simulation research; simulated environmental testing; and grants to universities and other research institutions. Id. § 2761(c). Trafigura contends that § 4611(b) imposes an unconstitutional tax under the Export Clause. It sought a refund for the amount it paid under § 4611(b). But the IRS denied the request. Trafigura then sued to challenge the constitutionality of § 4611(b). The district court agreed with Trafigura that § 4611(b) imposes an unconstitutional tax and granted the refund accordingly. The United States appealed. We review de novo the district court’s grant of summary judgment. Hernandez v. Reno, 91 F.3d 776, 779 (5th Cir. 1996). III. When it comes to federal power to tax exports, the text of Article I, Section 9 of the Constitution is categorical: “No Tax or Duty shall be laid on Articles exported from any State.” U.S. CONST. art. I, § 9, cl. 5. The ban on the power of the states to tax exports, by contrast, is less sweeping. It states that “[n]o State shall, without the Consent of the Congress, lay any Imposts or Duties on Imports or Exports, except what may be absolutely necessary for executing its inspection Laws.” U.S. CONST. art. I, § 10, cl. 2 (emphasis added). The inclusion of this exception in Article I, Section 10—allowing states to impose fees on exports that are “absolutely necessary for executing its inspection Laws”—naturally raises the question: Can the federal government impose similar fees on exports under Article I, Section 9? Trafigura might argue that the omission of this language from Article I, Section 9 was intentional and must be given meaning. See, e.g., Russello v. United States, 464 U.S. 16, 23 (1983) (courts generally presume that drafters act “intentionally and purposely in the disparate inclusion or exclusion” of language) (quotations omitted); United States v. Estrella, 758 F.3d 1239, 1252 (11th Cir. 2014) (“When language is included in one . . . provision but not included in another related provision, that omission has an important meaning that [courts] cannot ignore.”). But the United States might respond that Article I, Section 10 simply makes explicit what is implicit in Article I, Section 9—and that the Supreme Court has construed other provisions of the Constitution in a similar manner. See, e.g., Bolling v. Sharpe, 347 U.S. 497, 499–500 (1954) (applying equal protection principles to the federal government); Adarand Constructors, Inc. v. Pena, 515 U.S. 200, 213–17 (1995) (same). In any event, the Supreme Court has resolved this question. It has held that a federal “tax” on exports may be recharacterized—and upheld— as a “user fee,” if it is “designed as compensation for Government-supplied services, facilities, or benefits.” U.S. Shoe, 523 U.S. at 363. In doing so, however, the Supreme Court has cautioned that courts must carefully “guard against . . . the imposition of a duty under the pretext of fixing a fee.” Pace v. Burgess, 92 U.S. 372, 376 (1876). A. We must decide, then, whether § 4611(b) imposes a tax or a user fee. On its face, the text of § 4611(b) refers to the charge as a “tax.” But “we must regard things rather than names” and consider whether the charge functions as “a bona fide user fee.” U.S. Shoe, 523 U.S. at 367 (quotations omitted). Two Supreme Court decisions guide the analysis in this case—Pace and U.S. Shoe. Start with Pace—the “time-tested” and “guiding precedent for determining what constitutes a bona fide user fee in the Export Clause context.” Id. at 369. Pace involved a federal excise tax on tobacco. Congress specifically exempted tobacco intended for export from the excise tax. To combat fraud, however, Congress required all exported tobacco to bear a stamp on its packaging. The stamps cost exporters 25 cents per package (later reduced to 10 cents per package) and were “intended for no other purpose than to separate and identify the tobacco [intended for] export, and thereby, instead of taxing it, to relieve it from . . . taxation.” 92 U.S. at 375. The Court held that the stamp charge was a user fee, not a tax prohibited by the Export Clause. The charge was “in no sense a duty on exportation,” but was simply “compensation given for services properly rendered.” Id. The amount of the fees was “proper” and not “excessive.” Id. at 375–76. For example, “Congress did not limit the quantity or value of the tobacco packaged for export or the size of the stamped package; ‘these were unlimited, except by the discretion of the exporter or the convenience of handling.’” U.S. Shoe, 523 U.S. at 369 (quoting Pace, 92 U.S. at 375) (cleaned up, emphasis added). Two features of the stamp charge made it a user fee rather than an export tax, as the Court noted in Pace and reaffirmed in U.S. Shoe. First, it “bore no proportion whatever to the quantity or value of the package on which the stamp was affixed,” and second, it “was not excessive” given the cost of the services to prevent fraud and to “give the exporter the benefit of exemption from taxation.” Id. (cleaned up). Next up is U.S. Shoe, which involved a “harbor maintenance tax” applicable to “[e]xporters, importers, and domestic shippers” of commercial cargo passing through the nation’s ports. Id. at 363. The tax was computed on an ad valorem basis, in the amount of 0.125% of the cargo’s value. Proceeds were deposited into a trust fund used to finance harbor maintenance and development projects. Id. An exporter filed a protest with the Customs Service alleging the unconstitutionality of the toll “to the extent it applies to exports.” Id. at 363–64. The Court unanimously agreed that the ad valorem harbor maintenance charge was indeed an unconstitutional tax under the Export Clause, and not a permissible user fee. Id. at 363. As the Court explained, a charge is a user fee only if it “fairly match[es] the exporters’ use of” government services. Id. at 370. That wasn’t the case in U.S. Shoe. “The value of export cargo . . . does not correlate reliably with the federal harbor services used or usable by the exporter.” Id. at 369 (emphasis added). So the tax was barred by the Export Clause. Pace and U.S. Shoe tell us the following. First, we must consider whether the charge under § 4611(b) is based on the quantity or value of the exported oil—if so, then it is more likely a tax. Second, we must consider the connection between the Fund’s services to exporters, if any, and what exporters pay for those services under § 4611(b). That connection need not be a perfect fit. See Pace, 92 U.S. at 375–76. But a user fee must “fairly match” or “correlate reliably with” exporters’ use of government services. U.S. Shoe, 523 U.S. at 369–70. Finally, we apply “heightened scrutiny,” Matter of Buffets, LLC, 979 F.3d 366, 380 (5th Cir. 2020), and strictly enforce the Export Clause’s ban on taxes by “guard[ing] against . . . the imposition of a [tax] under the pretext of fixing a fee,” U.S. Shoe, 523 U.S. at 370 (quotations omitted). B. The United States admits, as it must, that the “amount of the [§ 4611(b)] charge is based on the volume of oil transported.” Exporters pay at a rate of 8 or 9 cents per “barrel”—or 8 or 9 cents per “42 United States gallons.” 26 U.S.C. §§ 4611(c)(2)(B), 4612(a)(8). This proportional fee scheme—more oil, more money—is true down to the fraction: “In the case of a fraction of a barrel, the tax imposed by section 4611 shall be the same fraction of the amount of such tax imposed on a whole barrel.” Id. § 4612(a)(9). So § 4611(b) is by design more like the tax in U.S. Shoe than the user fee in Pace. But the analysis does not end there. A charge is not a tax under the Export Clause simply because it is proportional to the quantity or value of the export. Under U.S. Shoe, we also consider whether the charge imposed by § 4611(b) fairly matches Trafigura’s use of government services. The United States claims that the charge operates essentially as a premium for government-provided insurance, in the form of capped liability for oil spills. Those who create more risk (i.e., by exporting more oil) pay a higher premium. And as for the various other government activities supported by the Fund, such as research and development for oil pollution technology, the United States characterizes them as “oil-spill-related services.” Based on that characterization, the United States concludes that the charge is a fee for those services, and not an effort to raise general revenue. Trafigura counters, however, that the charge does not offset the cost of any service that it receives from the government. It challenges the government’s insurance analogy. And it stresses that § 4611(b) finances a broad range of initiatives that are not “services” provided to exporters under any reasonable sense of the word. This last point is dispositive, so there is no need to address the government’s insurance analogy. A user fee is a charge for a specific service provided to, and used by, the payor. See U.S. Shoe, 523 U.S. at 369. A public agency might charge a user fee to visit a public park, tour a museum, or enter a toll road. In each case, you pay the fee, and in return, you get access to something of value— natural beauty and recreation, intellectual or aesthetic enrichment, uncongested roads. Put simply, user fees arise in the context of “value-for-value transaction[s].” Jensen, supra, at 37. There is no such discrete transaction here. Oil exporters subject to § 4611(b) are forced to pay for, among other things, reimbursements to federal, state, and Indian tribe trustees for assessing natural resource damage; research and development for oil pollution technology; studies into the effects of oil pollution; marine simulation research; and research grants to universities. See 33 U.S.C. §§ 2712(a), 2761(c). None of these things can plausibly be conceived as “services” provided to exporters in exchange for their payment. To be sure, exporters do benefit indirectly from these activities. But the same could be said for virtually every other tax. After all, the government is supposed to use tax proceeds to provide benefits for taxpayers. The fact that people pay taxes to fund police and fire protection does not somehow turn those taxes into user fees. Likewise, the fact that oil exporters like Trafigura also happen to benefit from the government’s “oil-spill-related” activities is beside the point—such benefits are not tied to a specific service that exporters receive as part of a value-for-value transaction. Exporters pay, society benefits. So this case is far afield from Pace. When an exporter pays the government for a stamp to shield the exporter from taxation, that is a value-for-value transaction that is exempt from the Export Clause. See 92 U.S. at 375 (stressing that “[t]he stamp was intended for no other purpose than to . . . relieve [exported tobacco] from the taxation to which other tobacco was subjected”). Here, by contrast, exporters subsidize a mishmash of anti-pollution measures for the general benefit of society. In sum, Congress has crafted a scheme in which crude oil exporters are forced to subsidize activities that are not “services used or usable by the exporter.” U.S. Shoe, 523 U.S. at 369. Section 4611(b) saddles exporters with the cost of anti-pollution measures that generally benefit society at large, and not specifically the exporter who pays the charge. C. A few words of response to the dissent. The dissent essentially theorizes that the oil industry, taken as a whole, causes oil spills, oil pollution, and environmental damage—and that the industry should therefore be held “responsible for [its] own actions and business practices.” Post, at 6 (Graves, J., dissenting). Forcing any industry or citizen to internalize their externalities is of course entirely reasonable as a policy matter. Many taxes are designed with precisely this goal in mind. Think of gasoline taxes designed to pay for road and infrastructure repair, mass transit, or air pollution mitigation—or carbon taxes crafted to force taxpayers to absorb the social cost of their emissions— or “sin taxes” on alcohol or gambling that are used to cover the cost of the social consequences of alcoholism or gambling addiction. These are commonplace measures designed to achieve important ends for society—ends that go well beyond merely defraying the costs of the government providing a particular service or benefit to members of the public. But that’s precisely what makes them a tax, rather than a fee. As the dissent’s theory confirms, this is not a “value-for-value” transaction, in which a feepayer pays the fee to receive a service or benefit in return, and is thus better off as a result of the transaction. See, e.g., U.S. Shoe, 523 U.S. at 363 (defining “‘user fee’” as “a charge designed as compensation for Government-supplied services, facilities, or benefits”); Pace, 92 U.S. at 374– 75 (upholding user fee to cover “the expense attending the providing and affixing [tobacco export] stamps” in order to “relieve [the exporter] from . . . taxation”). To the contrary, it’s a “penalty-for-penalty” transaction, in which the taxpayer is penalized for engaging in anti-social behavior that penalizes others. The dissent responds that the oil export tax is indeed a “value-for-value” transaction, because oil exporters pay the fee for the right to use our nation’s valuable natural resources to conduct their for-profit business. Post, at 7 n.8 (Graves, J., dissenting). But that proves too much. Every export tax can be characterized as payment for the right to use our nation’s resources to conduct one’s for-profit business, such as our stature and diplomatic prowess on the world stage, our defense and national security capabilities, and our access to international trade protections and governance structures. So under the dissent’s approach, Congress would be fully empowered to tax exports “under the pretext of fixing a fee.” Pace, 92 U.S. at 376. And that would contradict not just text but history as well. Delegates at the Constitutional Convention debated a last-minute suggestion to allow export taxes enacted for the purpose of “regulations of trade,” and to prohibit only those export taxes designed “for the purpose of revenue.” 2 Farrand, supra, at 363. But they quickly rejected the idea. If the Constitution forbids export taxes designed to further trade policy—and it plainly does—then there’s no principled basis to allow export taxes designed to further environmental policy. That would defy the plain text as well as the Founders’ understanding of our nation’s charter. And Alexander Hamilton would not just “get more than he gave”—he would get more than the Constitution permits. * * * We hold that § 4611(b) imposes a tax on exports in violation of the Export Clause. The United States may not enforce § 4611(b) on crude oil “exported from the United States.” We affirm. JAMES E. GRAVES, JR., Circuit Judge, dissenting: Because there are genuine issues of material fact as to whether 26 U.S.C. § 4611 imposes a legitimate user fee, I would vacate the district court’s grant of summary judgment on liability to Trafigura Trading LLC and remand. Thus, I respectfully dissent. Trafigura is a commodity trading company that purchases and exports crude oil from the United States. Trafigura asserts that it exported some 50 million barrels of oil from Texas, Louisiana and North Dakota between 2014 and 2017. As a result, Trafigura said that it paid in some $4,215,924 pursuant to 26 U.S.C. § 4611.[3] Trafigura later requested and was denied a refund for the amount paid. Trafigura then filed suit challenging the constitutionality of 26 U.S.C. § 4611 and seeking a refund of $4,215,924 collected pursuant to the statute. See 26 U.S.C. § 4611(b). The district court ultimately granted summary judgment on liability to Trafigura. The government appealed. Amounts collected under §4611(b) are transferred to the “Oil Spill Liability Trust Fund,” along with amounts collected via various other acts, to be used only for specific expenditures related to oil spills. See 26 U.S.C. §§ 9509(b), (c); see also 33 U.S.C. §§ 2712(a), 2761(e). The fund also provides a limitation on liability for the responsible party. See 33 U.S.C. § 2704; see also 33 U.S.C. §§ 2701(32) (definition of “responsible party”), and 2702 (elements of liability). The issue is whether 26 U.S.C. § 4611(b) levies an unconstitutional tax on crude oil under the Export Clause. See U.S. Const. art. I, § 9, cl. 5. The district court found that it does. The majority agrees. I disagree for the reasons stated herein. We review the district court’s grant of summary judgment de novo, applying the same standard as the district court. Naquin v. Elevating Boats, L.L.C., 817 F.3d 235, 238 (5th Cir. 2016). Summary judgment is proper where “the movant shows that there is no genuine dispute as to any material fact and the movant is entitled to judgment as a matter of law.” Fed. R. Civ. P. 56(a). We construe all facts and inferences in the light most favorable to the nonmoving party. Naquin, 817 F.3d at 238. The district court’s “function is not himself to weigh the evidence and determine the truth of the matter but to determine whether there is a genuine issue for trial.” Anderson v. Liberty Lobby, Inc., 477 U.S. 242, 249 (1986). Trafigura, the district court, and the plurality[4] cite Pace v. Burgess, 92 U.S. 372 (1876), and United States v. U.S. Shoe Corp., 523 U.S. 360 (1998) as controlling authority.[5] Pace involved a federal excise stamp on tobacco. Pace, 92 U.S. 372. The Supreme Court held that the stamp was a user fee, not an unconstitutional tax. Id. at 375 The plurality here “cleaned up” a quote from U.S. Shoe on the Court’s observations of Pace. The original quote states: The Court upheld the charge, concluding that it was “in no sense a duty on exportation,” but rather “compensation given for services [in fact] rendered.” In so ruling, the Court emphasized two characteristics of the charge: It “bore no proportion whatever to the quantity or value of the package on which [the stamp] was affixed”; and the fee was not excessive, taking into account the cost of arrangements needed both “to give to the exporter the benefit of exemption from taxation, and … to secure … against the perpetration of fraud.” U.S. Shoe, 523 U.S. at 369 (internal citations omitted) (alterations in original). In U.S. Shoe, the Supreme Court held that an ad valorem charge of 0.125% of the cargo’s value to finance harbor maintenance and development projects was an unconstitutional tax. Id. at 363. The Court distinguished Pace, saying: Pace establishes that, under the Export Clause, the connection between a service the Government renders and the compensation it receives for that service must be closer than is present here. Unlike the stamp charge in Pace, the [harbor charge] is determined entirely on an ad valorem basis. The value of export cargo, however, does not correlate reliably with the federal harbor services used or usable by the exporter. As the Federal Circuit noted, the extent and manner of port use depend on factors such as the size and tonnage of a vessel, the length of time it spends in port, and the services it requires, for instance, harbor dredging. U.S. Shoe, 523 U.S. 369 (citation omitted). The Court also reiterated that the Export Clause “does not rule out a user fee, provided that the fee lacks the attributes of a generally applicable tax or duty and is, instead, a charge designed as compensation for Government-supplied services, facilities, or benefits.” Id. at 363. The district court ostensibly relied on Pace and U.S. Shoe but then misapplied the standards set out in those cases in pronouncing a test which the plurality now adopts, saying: Pace and U.S. Shoe tell us the following. First, we must consider whether the charge under § 4611(b) is based on the quantity or value of the exported oil—if so, then it is more likely a tax. Second, we must consider the connection between the Fund’s services to exporters, if any, and what exporters pay for those services under § 4611(b). That connection need not be a perfect fit. See Pace, 92 U.S. at 375–76. But a user fee must “fairly match” or “correlate reliably with” exporters’ use of government services. Id. at 369–70. See also Trafigura Trading LLC v. United States, 485 F.Supp.3d 822, 826 (S.D. Tex. 2020). The plurality also includes a requirement of strict enforcement that does not appear in U.S. Shoe, which said”[i]n sum, if we are ‘to guard against … the imposition of a [tax] under the pretext of fixing a fee,’ [citing Pace, 92 U.S. at 376], and resist erosion of the Court’s [precedent], we must hold that the HMT violates the Export Clause as applied to exports.” U.S. Shoe, 523 U.S. at 370. Importantly, the Court also said, “[t]his does not mean that exporters are exempt from any and all user fees designed to defray the cost of harbor development and maintenance. It does mean, however, that such a fee must fairly match the exporters’ use of port services and facilities.” Id. I agree that Pace and U.S. Shoe are the applicable authority. But I disagree with the plurality’s characterization under the first part of the standard that “if so, then it is more likely a tax.” I also disagree with the plurality’s characterization of the second part that we only look at services. The plurality misapprehends Pace and repeatedly conflates quantity or volume with value. While the Pace court did say “[i]t bore no proportion whatever to the quantity or value of the package on which it was affixed,” the stamps were clearly required on each and every package of tobacco. Id. at 375. Thus, more packages equaled more stamps and more fees.[6] The same can be said here where the fees applied to each barrel and more barrels equal more fees. Also, importantly, the fees do not in any way depend on the value of the barrel.[7] The plurality’s statement that the fee here is more like the tax in U.S. Shoe than the user fee in Pace is unsupported. The fee here is not based on the value of the oil, as in U.S. Shoe. Instead, the per-barrel fee here is the equivalent of the per-package stamp in Pace. Under the second part, the plurality states that we must consider the government services provided to the exporters. However, U.S. Shoe says that we look to whether the fee is “designed as compensation for Government-supplied services, facilities, or benefits.” Id., 523 U.S. at 363. The U.S. Shoe Court held that the ad valorem tax was “not a fair approximation of services, facilities, or benefits furnished to the exporters.” Id. Here, the plurality essentially disregards the “services, facilities, or benefits” provided to the exporters by concluding that “[n]one of these things can plausibly be conceived as ‘services’ provided to exporters in exchange for their payment.” The plurality then concedes that “[t]o be sure, exporters do benefit indirectly from these activities” before attempting to equate exporting oil with police and fire protection. Specifically, the plurality says: But the same could be said for virtually every other tax. After all, the government is supposed to use tax proceeds to provide benefits for taxpayers. The fact that people pay taxes to fund police and fire protection does not somehow turn those taxes into user fees. Likewise, the fact that oil exporters like Trafigura also happen to benefit from the government’s “oil-spill related” activities is beside the point—such benefits are not tied to a specific service that exporters receive as part of a value-for-value transaction. Exporters pay, society benefits.[8] But that rationale is severely flawed and unsupported by the controlling authority. Neither Pace nor U.S. Shoe provide any requirement that only the exporter must benefit. Regardless, it is implausible to suggest that random taxpayers or random members of society are the primary beneficiaries of exporters simply being responsible for their own actions and business practices. There would be no oil spills, resulting damage, or need for research and development regarding oil pollution if oil was not exported. The oil was not exported by random taxpayers or random members of society, and they are neither responsible for any subsequent pollution/damage of precious natural resources nor the beneficiaries of any cap on liability.[9] The oil is exported by exporters, who are not forced to share any resulting profit with random taxpayers or random members of society. To borrow from the plurality, exporters pay and exporters benefit.[10] The plurality dismisses any suggestion that the oil industry generates the need for these anti-pollution measures as a matter of policy. However, cleaning up oil spills or restoring natural resources to their pre-damaged state are not merely policy motivations. The plurality further states that “Congress has crafted a scheme in which crude oil exporters are forced to subsidize activities that are not ‘services used or usable by the exporter.’ U.S. Shoe, 523 U.S. at 369.” What the U.S. Shoe Court actually said, though, is that “[t]he value of export cargo, however, does not correlate reliably with the federal harbor services used or usable by the exporter.” Id. “As the Federal Circuit noted, the extent and manner of port use depend on factors such as the size and tonnage of a vessel, the length of time it spends in port, and the services it requires, for instance, harbor dredging.” Id. Again, here, the fee is not based on the value of the oil. The charge of a fee per barrel is more akin to the above factors, like size and tonnage of a vessel, than any alleged “subsidizing” of “a mishmash of antipollution measures for the general benefit of society.”[11] The plurality cites no evidence in support of the conclusion that the nominal per-barrel fee does not reliably correlate to the services used or usable by the exporter. Moreover, the fee here is substantially less than the tax in U.S. Shoe and provides substantially more in return. Trafigura also asserts that exporters are solely responsible for paying the fee under § 4611. That is incorrect. The fee is not imposed on exporters; it is imposed on oil and its uses. See 26 U.S.C. § 4611. Trafigura is comingling separate sections and subsections when it says “nothing in § 4611 requires owners, operators, or demise charterers of vessels to pay § 4611(b) export taxes. See 26 U.S.C. § 4611(d)(3).” Subsection (d) states: Persons liable for tax.– Crude oil received at refinery.–The tax imposed by subsection (a)(1) shall be paid by the operator of the United States refinery. Imported petroleum product.–The tax imposed by subsection (a)(2) shall be paid by the person entering the product for consumption, use, or warehousing. Tax on certain uses or exports.–The tax imposed by subsection (b) shall be paid by the person using or exporting the crude oil, as the case may be. 26 U.S.C. § 4611(d). Despite Trafigura’s claims to the contrary, this provision explicitly lists multiple others who may be responsible for the fee, depending on the situation. Moreover, the language Trafigura searches for actually comes from 33 U.S.C. § 2701(32), which references “any person owning, operating, or demise chartering.” Additionally, the fee under § 4611(b) is only imposed if “before such use or exportation, no tax was imposed on such crude oil under subsection (a).” See § 4611(b)(1)(B). In other words, if someone else pays it pursuant to subsection (a), then it would not be imposed a second time under subsection (b). Simply because Trafigura was the appropriate person to pay here does not mean that only an exporter ever has to pay. Moreover, Trafigura is free to negotiate its contracts with other entities in a manner to attempt to recoup any required fees. Trafigura also asserts that exporters are omitted from the definition of “responsible party” and would not benefit from the liability limits. See 33 U.S.C. § 2701(32). That statement is also not entirely correct. While § 2701(32) does not specifically list “exporters,” it clearly lists numerous others, including “the owner of the oil being transported.” Trafigura acknowledges that it “purchases and exports domestic crude oil from the United States.” Thus, Trafigura concedes ownership of the oil in question which would establish its status as a potential responsible party. The plurality fails to distinguish this case from Pace; it fails to reference any facts to support its conclusion that the fees here were excessive or improper; and it fails to cite or apply the full standard of review. We are reviewing the district court’s grant of summary judgment; not weighing the evidence or determining the truth of the matter. Anderson, 477 U.S. at 249. This court is required to construe all facts and inferences in the light most favorable to the government. See Naquin, 817 F.3d at 238. “[C]ourts may not resolve genuine disputes of fact in favor of the party seeking summary judgment.” Tolan v. Cotton, 572 U.S. 650, 656 (2014). As set out herein, Trafigura failed to show that there is no genuine dispute of material fact or that it was entitled to judgment as a matter of law. Thus, summary judgment was improper. For these reasons, I would vacate the district court’s grant of summary judgment on liability to Trafigura and remand. Accordingly, I respectfully dissent.

 
Reprints & Licensing
Mentioned in a Law.com story?

License our industry-leading legal content to extend your thought leadership and build your brand.

More From ALM

With this subscription you will receive unlimited access to high quality, online, on-demand premium content from well-respected faculty in the legal industry. This is perfect for attorneys licensed in multiple jurisdictions or for attorneys that have fulfilled their CLE requirement but need to access resourceful information for their practice areas.
View Now
Our Team Account subscription service is for legal teams of four or more attorneys. Each attorney is granted unlimited access to high quality, on-demand premium content from well-respected faculty in the legal industry along with administrative access to easily manage CLE for the entire team.
View Now
Gain access to some of the most knowledgeable and experienced attorneys with our 2 bundle options! Our Compliance bundles are curated by CLE Counselors and include current legal topics and challenges within the industry. Our second option allows you to build your bundle and strategically select the content that pertains to your needs. Both options are priced the same.
View Now
September 18, 2024 - September 19, 2024
Dallas, TX

Join General Counsel and Senior Legal Leaders at the Premier Forum Designed For and by General Counsel from Fortune 1000 Companies


Learn More
October 15, 2024
Dallas, TX

The Texas Lawyer honors attorneys and judges who have made a remarkable difference in the legal profession in Texas.


Learn More
April 29, 2024 - May 01, 2024
Aurora, CO

The premier educational and networking event for employee benefits brokers and agents.


Learn More

Truly exceptional Bergen County New Jersey Law Firm is growing and seeks strong plaintiff's personal injury Attorney with 5-7 years plaintif...


Apply Now ›

Shipman is seeking an associate to join our Labor & Employment practice in our Hartford, New Haven, or Stamford office. Candidates shou...


Apply Now ›

McCarter & English, LLP, a well established and growing law firm, is actively seeking a talented and driven associate having 2-5 years o...


Apply Now ›
04/29/2024
The National Law Journal

Professional Announcement


View Announcement ›
04/15/2024
Connecticut Law Tribune

MELICK & PORTER, LLP PROMOTES CONNECTICUT PARTNERS HOLLY ROGERS, STEVEN BANKS, and ALEXANDER AHRENS


View Announcement ›
04/11/2024
New Jersey Law Journal

Professional Announcement


View Announcement ›