X

Thank you for sharing!

Your article was successfully shared with the contacts you provided.
Consider the following developments over the last year. Visa International and MasterCard Inc. settled antitrust litigation brought by Wal-Mart Stores Inc. for $3 billion over the allegation that the card businesses illegally tied use of debit card to credit card purchases. The European Union announced a decision to impose a fine of $600 million on Microsoft Corp. for, among other things, its incorporation of a media player into its Windows computer operating system. See Caroline E. Mayer, “Visa Settles Suit Over Debit Cards,” Wash. Post, May 1, 2003, at E1; James Kanter, Don Clark and John R. Wilke, “EU Imposes Sanctions on Microsoft,” Wall St. J., March 25, 2004, at A2. The “tying” doctrine, here and overseas, has become the crowbar with which virtually every business now can be threatened. A quick review of the doctrine suggests that although some courts have made progress in understanding why businesses combine particular features in the packages they sell to the public, others still rigidly adhere to the tying doctrine. The tying doctrine prohibits (under certain circumstances) the connection of two goods for sale as a package. This doctrine began with a simple view of what tying was all about: The firm could use the product that was intensely demanded to generate sales of a less popular product. Courts viewed that tie as inimical to competition and to consumers. And some of the early cases looked, at least on the surface, as though they fit that pattern. Not surprisingly, then, the courts adopted a per se rule that made tie-ins illegal when the seller had market power in the intensely demanded product. Over time, the tying doctrine has come under considerable pressure. Two observations lie at the core of this pressure. First, commentators observed that the connection of more and less popular (more and less intensely demanded) goods did not, except in the most unusual conditions, confer advantage on the firm. The “one monopoly rent” argument asserts that a firm with market power can extract the benefit of that power only once-by raising the price of the good it has power over-and that the firm can change the form of the rent extraction but not the magnitude. Although that assertion left room for debate about just which conditions allowed a shift of profits to the tying firm, economists generally agreed the basic argument was correct. Second, observers recognized that tying is not a rare and suspicious practice. Quite the contrary: It is ubiquitous, commonly done by firms with little or no market power as well as by dominant firms. Hotels bundle rooms with robes and towels, shampoo and chocolates-and no one thinks their hotel should be offering them a choice of competing vendors for the amenities, even if they might prefer another brand or item. Law firms offer the services of their senior lawyers in combination with those of their more junior lawyers-and no one thinks that partners in one firm should be required to offer clients a choice of associates from other firms. Cars are sold with audio, DVD and air-conditioning systems. Shoes are sold with laces even though shoestores also sell laces independently. The list of packages-of tie-ins-is endless. Virtually all products and services are sold as combinations of items or features that could be-and often are-also sold separately. When companies tie goods together as packages, with no market power in either good, the reasons for tying cannot primarily be the extension or leveraging of monopoly power. Instead, efficiencies-lower cost to producers and lower cost or higher value to consumers-provide the general explanation for tying in those situations. The European Union’s antitrust regulators have a different perspective; they seem far more concerned with preventing disadvantage to competing businesses than with promoting efficiencies that benefit consumers. Over the past two decades, however, U.S. courts responded to the arguable mistake of tying doctrine-of labeling tying as so clearly inimical to consumers as to be branded per se illegal-with various efforts to step back from its more extreme consequences. The U.S. Supreme Court’s decision in Jefferson Parish Hospital Dist. v. Hyde, 466 U.S. 2 (1984), for instance, attempted to separate instances in which there are obvious, pervasive inefficiencies of separate provision of goods-so pervasive that there was not an independent market for the tied good. The court retained the per se rule in form, but it relied on analysis of the markets for the tied and tying goods that functionally moved the doctrine closer to a neutral standard. Four justices would have gone further and adopted a “rule of reason” analysis (an unstructured inquiry into the efficiency benefits and competitive effects of the practice in each specific instance). Jefferson Parish marks an important step in the development of the tying doctrine, but it ultimately does little to reverse the initial mistake. After all, almost all tied goods do have independent markets. There plainly are separate markets for bathrobes and towels and chocolates, even if it is grossly inefficient for hotels to separate those items from the room. Hotels tie the items together when leaving the provision of these items to the traveler reduces the value of the package by more than the cost savings to the hotel. The same is true for joint provision of automobiles and audio systems and for many other bundles. Failure to recognize this point left the law in limbo, with some opportunity to except efficient bundling from tying law but with the onus largely on defendants to carve their conduct out from the presumption that tying was improper. The U.S. ‘Microsoft’ decision Another step in the development of tying law came in the U.S. litigation over Microsoft Corp.’s evolving Windows platform for personal computers. The U.S. Department of Justice claimed that Microsoft violated antitrust law by bundling its Explorer Web browser with its Windows operating system. The Web browser was one of many features that over time went from options available strictly on a stand-alone basis to being integrated parts of the Windows platform. Indeed, Windows was created by bundling the DOS operating system with a (formerly separate) graphical user interface. The U.S. Circuit Court for the District of Columbia rejected the district judge’s conclusion that the Web browser’s integration into Windows created an illegal tie-in. United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34 (D.C. Cir.), cert denied, 534 U.S. 952 (2001). It rooted this rejection largely in its understanding of the market forces that support bundling. Going beyond Jefferson Parish, the Microsoft III decision (as this one is commonly referred to) recognized that there typically are efficiencies in combining features that could be offered on a stand-alone basis. The court observed that bundling can increase value to consumers and can take advantage of economies of scope that lower costs. It noted that software producers, whether plausibly having market power or not, commonly integrate new features into their software. The court saw that in platform markets especially, integration could help software developers, as well as consumers, by reducing the costs of other software products that would be added on to the platform. The court, therefore, adopted a rule-of-reason approach, under which the government would bear the burden of showing that the harm to competition from integration of features into software outweighs its efficiency benefits. This test, which the Microsoft III court expressly limited to software tying cases, is a far cry from the presumption that tying is per se illegal. Far more than under European competition doctrine, the rule-of-reason approach seems in keeping with an understanding of why all software firms bundle features together rather than sell each one discretely and why software programs grow over time to house more and more features that once were sold separately. Microsoft III’s test stops well shy of acknowledging that the practice the court was addressing-and the problem with treating the practice as presumptively illicit-was not peculiar to the software business. The court also set forth a test that does not readily distinguish the problematic tie from the ordinary, market-driven integration of features and that leaves a great deal of discretion to the decision-maker in the particular case. Microsoft III‘s rejection of the per se illegality approach clearly goes a step beyond Jefferson Parish in its recognition of the efficiencies of tying. Before software businesses crack open the champagne to celebrate, however, they should think about two things. First, the new rule-of-reason test for software integration, although more lenient than the hybrid per se test generally applied to tying, is actually a more restrictive test than the one courts traditionally have applied to the physical integration of existing products. In this sense, Microsoft III will appear to some as a step backward along tying law’s path. Second, software businesses should consider the difficulties that arise under the rule-of-reason test. How will the burden of proof ultimately be allocated by courts? How will anti-competitive harms be determined-by the complaints of rival software firms or by proof of harm to the typical consumer? Will the test accommodate instances in which efficiencies are likely to be realized only after several years have passed? Will allowance be made for “honest mistakes” in business judgment, as when a firm takes a competitive action that harms a rival and the resulting efficiencies are weaker, or further delayed, than anticipated? How much weight should be put on market share in software markets, where consumer herding imparts volatility to market share statistics? Given the continuing pressures on the per se illegality rule, the future of tying law depends on how courts answer these questions. A rule-of-reason test that makes sense in light of tying’s efficiencies, in software and in other markets, would set a high standard of proof-perhaps requiring “clear and convincing” evidence-and put the burden on the plaintiff. A test that aims for a formal neutrality by imposing significant proof burdens on the defendant would leave many businesses in the position they are in today, uncertain about the liability risks of tying. When the vast majority of ties are efficient, as observation suggests, the proper resting point for tying doctrine would seem to be on the other end of the spectrum from its per se illegality starting point: something close in operation to a presumption of legality. But after Wal-Mart and the European Union’s Microsoft decision, the path toward such a tying doctrine will be a long one. Ronald A. Cass is dean and Melville Madison Bigelow Professor at the Boston University School of Law. Keith N. Hylton is professor and Paul J. Liacos Scholar-in-Law at the law school. Both have served as consultants to Microsoft, and Cass has served as a consultant to the U.S. Department of Justice’s Antitrust Division, but neither is directly involved in any of the litigation discussed in this article.

This content has been archived. It is available exclusively through our partner LexisNexis®.

To view this content, please continue to Lexis Advance®.

Not a Lexis Advance® Subscriber? Subscribe Now

Why am I seeing this?

LexisNexis® is now the exclusive third party online distributor of the broad collection of current and archived versions of ALM's legal news publications. LexisNexis® customers will be able to access and use ALM's content by subscribing to the LexisNexis® services via Lexis Advance®. This includes content from the National Law Journal®, The American Lawyer®, Law Technology News®, The New York Law Journal® and Corporate Counsel®, as well as ALM's other newspapers, directories, legal treatises, published and unpublished court opinions, and other sources of legal information.

ALM's content plays a significant role in your work and research, and now through this alliance LexisNexis® will bring you access to an even more comprehensive collection of legal content.

For questions call 1-877-256-2472 or contact us at [email protected]

 
 

ALM Legal Publication Newsletters

Sign Up Today and Never Miss Another Story.

As part of your digital membership, you can sign up for an unlimited number of a wide range of complimentary newsletters. Visit your My Account page to make your selections. Get the timely legal news and critical analysis you cannot afford to miss. Tailored just for you. In your inbox. Every day.

Copyright © 2020 ALM Media Properties, LLC. All Rights Reserved.